Tuesday, March 29, 2011

Is a Soda Tax Politically Feasible?


Back in 2009, the two largest “Big Soda” beverage producers in the united states – the Coca-Cola Company and Pepsi Co – and the American Beverage Association (ABA) – an organization that lobbies on behalf of beverage companies – spent an unprecedented $37.5 million on lobbying members of congress to kill a proposed national sales tax on soft drinks that would, in part, help to cover costs associated with healthcare reform. Americans might not perceive beverage companies as having the same political influence on par with big oil and pharma, but make no mistake, these companies are also powerful and just as committed to protecting their corporate interests. Having lost the fight for a soda tax in congress, health advocates are now taking the battle to individual states. In doing so, they should turn to Arkansas to learn from the states experience in passing and preserving a soda tax.

As early as 1992, Arkansas passed a soda tax that the beverage lobby and state chamber of commerce said would kill business in the state. The tax added an additional 2 cents per 12 ounces of soda, a negligible amount, especially when compared to what is being proposed these days. The beverage companies, however, would have none of it, fearing less that the action would directly hit profits, and more that if it proved successful, copy cat legislation would be proposed in state legislatures across the country. In an effort to squelch the newly passed bill, “Big Soda” poured substantial resources into a voter referendum campaign to repeal the law in 1994, but to no avail. Voters rejected the proposition to repeal the tax by a healthy margin of 55-to-45 percent. In 1997, “Big Soda” tried once again to repeal the law, this time through the state’s legislature, and was again unsuccessful.

Why was there so much support for this tax in a state that is not known for having liberal tax policies or producing progressive legislation? The reason that the tax was able to pass the legislature and then withstand numerous attempts at its repeal was due, in large part, to how the revenue was allocated. Money generated by the soda tax was earmarked as an additional funding source for the state’s hugely popular Medicaid program. Tying the soda tax – something that has the potential of being politically unpopular because it's a tax, but more so, because it's a tax on a highly visible good – to a popular social program, greatly enhanced the political feasibility it needed to become law and withstand repeal.

Furthermore, in an effort to have the Arkansas law repealed in 1997, the Arkansas Hospitality Association argued that the tax would impair profit margins for businesses operating in the state, resulting in a loss of business to adjacent states. U.S. labor statistics, however, tell a different story. It showed that “employment in the food and drink services sector increased by 6 percent in the two years after the soda tax was adopted, the highest increase since the Labor Department began collecting the data. From 1992 to 2008 private employment in Arkansas' Food Services and Drinking Places increased by 57.5 percent, twice the rate of total private sector employment in the state."[i]

While there doesn’t seem to be any substantial evidence that the Arkansas soda tax has dissuaded individuals from purchasing high calorie soft drinks, and therefore has done little to influence consumer behavior,[ii] it does prove that taxes on goods with adverse affects are feasible if those revenues are then used to mitigate the negative externalities associated with that particular good.[iii] [iv] If the objective is to reduce soda consumption rather than raise revenue, the Arkansas tax would have to be much higher to have a significant impact.[v] If taxes were increased on an elastic product such as soft drinks, then evidence shows that consumption of that good would decrease substantially, as has been the case with tobacco.[vi]

It is difficult to determine whether a substantially higher tax would be equally as feasible from a political perspective, but it would result in changes to consumer behavior. A review conducted by the Yale University's Rudd Center for Food Policy and Obesity found that for every 10 percent increase in price, soda consumption likely decreases by 8 percent.[vii] The effects are likely higher for heavy users of soft drinks.[viii] Based on November 2008 price increase and volume sales information on Coca Cola and Pepsi sales in the U.S., soda elasticity demand is negative 1.15 meaning that a 10% tax would reduce consumption by 11.5 percent.[ix] Ultimately, the key to increasing the political feasibility of a soda tax is to use statistical evidence showing that a moderate soda tax won’t stifle economic vitality and that revenues are earmarked for popular programs that benefit society.


[i]Dreier, P. a. (2010, April 20). The Soda Tax Wars: Huffpost Food. Retrieved April 29, 2011, from huffingtonpost: http://www.huffingtonpost.com/peter-dreier/the-soda-tax-wars_b_544898.html?page=3

[ii] Smith, D. (2009, Septemaber 03). Will the Soda Tax Go National: Arkansas Times. Retrieved April 29, 2011, from Arkansas Times: http://www.arktimes.com/arkansas/will-the-soda-pop-tax-go-national/Content?oid=949896

[iii] Center on Budget and Policy Priorities. (2009, May 27). Tax - Federal: Center on Budget and Policy. Retrieved April 29, 2011, from Center on Budget and Policy: http://www.cbpp.org/cms/index.cfm?fa=view&id=2830

[iv] Stobbe, M. (2010, April 1). HuffPost Denver: The Huffington Post. Retrieved April 29, 2011, from The Huffington Post Web site: http://www.huffingtonpost.com/2010/04/01/colorado-soda-tax-study-s_n_521481.html

[v] CBS News. (2010, April 1). Health: CBS News. Retrieved April 29, 2011, from CBSNews.com: http://www.cbsnews.com/stories/2010/04/01/health/main6353297.shtml

[vi] World Health Organization. (2009). Tobacco Free Initiative (TFI): World Health Organization. Retrieved April 29, 2011, from World Health Organization Web site: http://www.who.int/tobacco/mpower/2009/gtcr_download/en/index.html

[vii] Andreyeva, T., Long, M. W., and Brownell, K. D. (2008). The impact of food prices on consumption: A systematic review of research on price elasticity of demand for food.

[viii] Gustavsen, G. W., and Rickertsen, K. (2005). Public policies and the demand for carbonated soft drinks. Working paper prepared for presentation at the XIth Congress of the European Association of Agricultural Economists, Copenhagen, Denmark, August 24-27, 2005.

[ix] Beverage Digest, November 21, 2008, pp 3-4.

Examining New Hampshire's Statewide Property Tax

In 2009, New Hampshire’s combined state and local tax burden ranked 44th of the 50 states.[1] This is achieved, in part, by having no state general sales or use tax and no tax on income from wages. Instead, the state and local governments rely heavily on the property tax for revenues. As such, New Hampshire has one of the highest levels of property taxes in the nation.[2] The New Hampshire statewide property tax rate is determined by the amount of revenue that is needed, approximately $363 million (New Hampshire Department of Education, 2011). The 2010 rate was $2.190 per $1,000 equalized valuations (Transparent NH).

EFFICIENCY: The New Hampshire statewide property tax appears to be an efficient tax. Behavior changes seem minimal as a result of the tax. Both homeownership rates and home size are higher in New Hampshire than the national average.

EQUITY: The New Hampshire statewide property tax was instituted because of inequities in education funding. Now, the statewide property tax funds the public school system, a public education system that is better than at least 40 states in the nation[3]. In addition, the state instituted property tax relief for low to moderate-income homeowners[4]. To read more about the history of low and moderate-income homeowners property tax relief click here. [5] However, the traditional view of property tax is regressive, that is the lower tax brackets pay a higher share of their income than those in higher tax brackets.

ADEQUACY: The adequacy of the statewide property tax to generate revenue is about average. On one hand, the tax base is fairly large which allows the state to collect quite a bit of money. Property taxes are also more stable than sales or income taxes. However, property taxes are one of the most hated taxes and are often subject to property tax limits, constraining revenue generation for local governments. They also have a lower tax elasticity, or ability for tax revenues to keep up with changes in income, than sales or income taxes. Property taxes as revenue producers are increasingly falling short and often do not keep pace with the financial needs of local governments; leading many states to introduce additional taxes such as income or sales taxes.

FEASIBILITY: The use of a property tax to solve the education-funding crisis was relatively simple and highly administratively feasible for New Hampshire, it merely added onto an existing tax without increasing these drawbacks. The political feasibility of the property tax however was a bit more difficult. The New Hampshire Supreme Court required equalization in school funding, however, New Hampshire citizens have historically been resistant to tax increases. While any tax increase would inevitably be unpopular, among the choices, this was the least unpopular.

Political leaders and citizens alike are currently debating a tax overhaul in New Hampshire. Is now the time? What should they do? Click for the articles A Tax Revolt Grows in New Hampshire and Some Call for State Tax System Overhaul for the latest dialogue on New Hampshire's tax system.

[1] http://www.taxfoundation.org/taxdata/show/468.html

[2] http://www.taxfoundation.org/taxdata/show/251.html

[3] http://www.pelhamweb.com/assessor/NOT%20AS%20HIGH%20AS%20YOU%20THINK.pdf

[4] http://www.nh.gov/revenue/faq/dra_1200.htm

[5] http://www.nh.gov/revenue/forms/documents/LM_history.pdf

Brilliance or Big Brother? The VMT Tax

Angry about those mammoth potholes that are resurfacing as the snow melts? Many craters in Minnesotan roads go unfilled partially because of the insufficiency of fuel tax funds to fully cover the maintenance of federal, state and local transportation infrastructure. At a national average of 48.1 cents per gallon, the decline of the effective tax rate and a recent trend in fuel-efficient cars (which has led to decreases in fuel consumption) has lessened both the efficiency and adequacy of the excise gas tax. To address this dilemma, many policymakers are taking a second look at the vehicle miles traveled (VMT) tax. Instead of taxing by the gallon, the VMT tax is based on the distance traveled– a direct user-fee for driving on roads. The tax utilizes GPS technology in the form of a small, on-vehicle-device (OVD) which collects miles traveled and transmits that information electronically when drivers fuel up at the pump.

Despite its potential, many serious concerns arise when considering the efficiency, adequacy, equity and feasibility of the VMT tax:

  • Efficiency: Compared to the fuel tax, the VMT tax has the potential to change driver behavior in a positive way by reducing average daily mileage (moving society to a more socially beneficial equilibrium in terms of congestion and pollution). Also, if the VMT was designed to charge more during peak periods, the transportation system would become more efficient by reducing congestion and distributing trips more evenly across multiple modes.

  • Adequacy: As the VMT tax can be imposed on every vehicle for each mile driven regardless of fuel efficiency/type, it will have a more complete tax base and still relatively low tax rates, thus having a higher tax adequacy relative to fuel tax. Also, the sustainability is enhanced since fluctuating fuel prices, increasing fuel efficiency and alternative fuels would have a lesser impact on VMT tax revenue.

  • Equity: Unlike the fuel tax, the VMT tax is not influenced by fuel efficiency or fuel type, improving equity in terms of benefits received and horizontal equity. However, considering vertical equity, a flat-rate VMT tax is still highly regressive, though to a lesser-extent compared to the fuel tax. A possible way to improve vertical equity is applying a higher tax rate to luxury sport cars than vehicles for ordinary uses.

  • Feasibility: Due to incredibly high public visibility and low opportunity for tax exportation, the VMT tax faces major political feasibility issues. On the administrative side, costs needed to develop new accounting systems, technology, and infrastructure at each gas station (and on every vehicle) are daunting. Yet privacy concerns are paramount when considering the overall feasibility of the VMT tax, as many assert that the tracking device impinges on their freedom and hearkens back to “Big Brother” government:

Despite these concerns, as more and more people change their consumption habits away from gasoline, will the burgeoning holes in transportation budgets around the country change public opinion of the VMT tax from “Big Brother” to revenue brilliance?

The Minneapolis Downtown Improvement District

Have you noticed any change to our downtown district has become cleaner, safer, greener and better? Thanks for Andy‘s blog about special service district, which ignites our group to further explore Minneapolis Downtown Improvement District(DID). DID was formed in early 2009 after more than 5 years of formative planning and advocacy by the Minneapolis Downtown Council. As economic rational peeople, each of us may ask: why would we like to take more money from our skinny pockets for public services under difficult economic times? Why is the DID service different than from other government actions?

DID is one type of business improvement districts (BID). As we have learned some public services are more efficient when they are carried out by lower level government, they can understand and satisfy local residents’ unique characters and preference. BID is a new public-private partnership stemming from the idea that today’s entrepreneurial leaders know how to improve their business as while as improve their community. Therefore, “the basic approach for BID is one in which a majority of businesses defined by geographic location agree to provide an extra level of public service in their area by imposing an added tax or fee on all the properties or business in the area. The job of local government is to legally establish the district, collect the special tax assessments, and then transfer the funds over to a BID organization to use as it sees fit.”(Jerry Mitchell) Hundreds of BIDs have been operating in 42 states today. The successful examples are Washington DC Business Improvement District, Alliance for New York Downtown, etc.

In the Minneapolis Downtown Improvement District a non-profit entity is working with three committees: Operations& services budget, Greening design & infrastructure and DID communications. Currently DID is providing services which clean the streets, improve sidewalk experiences, provide safety services and plant greenery with DID ambassadors who are on the streets. Below is a video the DID created to promote their services.

DID is funded largely by charges to commercial properties that are included as special assessments on property tax invoices. It is interesting to see how DID separates downtown area into three types of district and provides different scale services to each district, please check their maps by block number and service level.. You can also find their annual report and operating plan on the DID website. Below is their working result in between July 2009 and June 2010:

Can DID make a difference? They claim DID is 100% business managed, utilizing sound business principles and the same quality and cost control by businesses when managing private properties. We can view DID like a “tiny government” charging tax to provide extra services for public values. We can also view DID like a business company charging fees to provide special services we want. DID, as a type of public-and-private partnership, may has advantages like bringing innovation, private expertise, competition and serving better public interest.

Blog by Peter Hamma, Lyssa Leitner, Rose Ryan, Paul Teicher, and Yizhuo (Serene) Zhao


A clothing sales tax? If the shoe fits...

Minnesota residents have benefitted from the exemption of clothing from the sales tax base since 1967. However, given Minnesota's $5 billion deficit, some Minnesota legislators are proposing a clothing sales tax (2:20 minute video) in an attempt to raise revenue, expand the tax base, and bypass having to make cuts.

Clothing Tax Comparison

Indeed, of the states that do collect sales taxes, only Minnesota, New Jersey, Pennsylvania, and Rhode Island completely exempt clothing from taxation; Connecticut, Massachusetts, Vermont and New York offer partial exemptions. None of Minnesota’s neighbors exempt clothing from taxation.

Clothing Tax Stack-up

Efficiency
Since all neighboring states impose a sales tax on clothing, it is unlikely that Minnesota residents would travel elsewhere to purchase clothing. The two likely places for distortion would be in internet sales and the potential negative impact on tourism- particularly in border cities and at the Mall of America.


Equity

A sales tax on clothing, especially with regards to smaller purchases, would be highly regressive as it would constitute a greater burden on lower-income households than on higher-income households. And while a $6.875 charge on a $100 purchase (given Minnesota’s 6.875% sales tax) might not seem very great, it represents a significant amount for families that might spend $300 on clothing . Ask anyone who’s had to buy shoes for growing children!


Feasibility

Implementing a clothing sales tax in Minnesota will be highly visible to the public, and grumbles would likely ensue. On the positive side, a clothing sales tax is highly exportable to non-residents. For instance, it is well known that people travel across the country to shop at the Mall of America, so the state will be able to collect revenue from tourist shoppers. The administrative feasibility of enforcing a clothing sales tax is fairly straight-forward. The state already has the administrative capacity to collect sales tax on a variety of products.

Adequacy

If simply looking at these measures to determine if expanding the Minnesota sales tax to clothing would provide to be adequate, then we would say yes. However, at the current rate, the sales tax on clothing is projected to provide $566 million in FY2012-2013. This amount is not adequate to cover the total projected budget deficit, but there isn't one solution that could. Another consideration is the stability of the tax as a revenue source. Generally, the goals of a good tax system are advanced by having broader tax bases and lower tax rates.

Important Considerations

The unique factor to the current legislative proposal on extending the sales tax to clothing, is where that additional revenue is to be directed. In the video below, Senate Tax Chair Tom Bakk, states that the additional monies are to be directed to the Minnesota school fund, in order to increase that pot of money.

Additionally, over the years 2011 – 2013, the tax rate on clothes is to be lowered. By lowering the rate over time, and maintaining the same payment to the school fund, any surplus in revenue will actually have a negative net impact on the General Fund. The state is raising additional revenue through the expansion of the sales tax to clothing, yet lowering its ability to raise revenue by eventually decreasing the tax rate, and therefore negating its ability to successfully be used to fund a specific program, and again creating a deficit.

What do you think? Should MN "fold" on the clothing tax proposal? Why or why not?

The European model for Internet sales taxation

Countries around the world have taken significantly divergent approaches to Internet sales revenue capture. In 1998, the European Union looked to implement the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development’s (OECD) framework for taxing the emerging e-commerce sector. The centerpiece of this framework is that taxation of a good or service should be done in the jurisdiction where the consumption took place. Additionally, the OECD stated that no one type of commerce should receive special treatment over another. In the outline the OECD argued that:
Taxation should seek to be neutral and equitable between conventional and electronic forms of commerce. Business decisions should be motivated by economic rather than tax considerations. Taxpayers in similar situations carrying out similar transactions should be subject to similar levels of taxation.[1]
In 2002, the European Union (EU) passed legislation requiring all its member nations to collect Internet sales tax transactions between businesses and consumers. Companies in the EU were expected to complete the necessary registration and were given the specific software to begin collecting taxes from online sales transactions (Here is registration process for companies in the United Kingdom). All member nations levy a value added tax (VAT) of 15-25 percent of the price of the good depending on the VAT rate in their country. Originally the provisions required that EU member states collect this tax on all transactions including ones with non-member states. In an effort to ensure that European companies were not put at a competitive disadvantage internationally they amended these provisions in 2003 to only require collecting taxes from EU member states.
The European Union has decided how they are going to address the emerging issue of Internet sales taxation. As the graph and news report below shows, Internet retail sales in the United States are drastically increasing and the country will need to make a decision on how they are going to approach the complicated revenue subject.

The news agency does not allow embedding of their content. Please click on the icon to view the video Tax Free Internet Shopping Could End Soon.

you tube



[1] Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD). Electronic Commerce: Taxation Framework Conditionshttp://www.oecd.org/dataoecd/46/3/1923256.pdf Oct. 8, 1998

Local Option Sales Taxes in the Omnibus Tax Bills

The 2011 legislative session has been a nail biter for local governments in Minnesota. On Monday, the House passed the Tax Committee’s omnibus bill by a vote of 73-59. Rep. Davids, committee chair, said the aim of the bill is to create jobs and reduce the tax burden on Minnesotans. In contrast, House Minority Leader Paul Thissen called it, “handcuffs that chain us into awful choices.” Local option sales tax (LOST) restrictions have become points of contention in the House bill.

Tensions are running especially high in Rochester. House members removed a $58.5 million local option sales tax from the omnibus tax bill. One member of the Rochester Area Chamber of Commerce vehemently spoke out against the bill and told State Legislators to stop controlling local governments’ purse strings, “Rochester is fully capable of making intelligent decisions as to how we want to spend our money, and don't tread in that area is my recommendation to you because it is a hot subject in town.” Rochester has a history of fighting for local control of LOSTs. In 2008, the legislature imposed a moratorium on LOSTs that expired in May 2010. In 2010, Rochester worked hard to defeat an extension of the moratorium. Although the moratorium expired last May, the House bill re-imposes it by prohibiting local government spending to promote new local sales taxes until May 2012 (it does not affect LOST approved by May 24, 2011).

Hennepin County has also been keeping an ear tuned to the debates in St. Paul. Supporters and opponents of a LOST proposal to fund the Twins stadium packed a 600 seat auditorium to testify before the House Tax Committee. The proposal includes a .15 percent increase in sales tax, which amounts to about 3 cents per $20.

There is a glimmer of hope (or hurdle, depending on your point of view) for local governments like Rochester and Hennepin County. The House bill is now moving to the Senate, where it must be reconciled with the Senate Tax Committee omnibus bill. The Senate version does not renew the moratorium and authorizes a different set of LOST proposals.

LOST advocates have reason to be hopeful. Sen. Julianne Ortman, Chair of the Senate Tax Committee, has supported greater local control over LOSTs. She recently told MPR that allowing local governments more flexibility to raise their own revenue could be more efficient than forcing them to get permission from the legislature to impost local sales taxes. Although she introduced a bill to that effect, it is not included in the Senate omnibus tax bill.

Local governments around the state are anxiously (or eagerly) waiting to see what the final tax bill will look like and how it will impact their revenue options. John James, former Commissioner of Revenue and founder of Sensible Tax and Fiscal Systems, predicted that sales tax reform would be one result of this legislative session. Governments like Rochester and Hennepin County must be wondering if that includes new restrictions on local option sales taxes.